'The origins of Political Order' - Francis Fukuyama - review
Fukuyama first
won major acclaim with his overly optimistic article claimed that history ended
in 1989 at the fall of the Berlin Wall.
While his thesis was certainly disputed by conflict in the Balkans and
then destroyed events in the middle east since, it spawned an impressive book
in 1992, review here. In this book,
Fukuyama refrains from prophesising and evaluates the genesis of the state.
This work is
an impressive blend of anthropology, social biology, history and political
science. In this volume, Fukuyama goes
in search of the origins of modern government – something so essential to our
lives that we forget how arduous it was to create in the first place, assuming
conscious acts were involved rather than necessity.
Starting
with the altruistic and co-operative behaviour observable in chimps – Fukuyama
traces the evolution of hunter-gathering bands into tribes, which, with the aid
of religion, transformed themselves into states so as to more effectively make
war.
Unlike
tribes, states did not disintegrate with the death of a charismatic leader, and
hence were seen as guaranteeing a better chance of survival. Attila the Hun or
Genghis Khan were here today, gone tomorrow; the Han or Ming dynasties endured
for centuries. Across the globe the key process was to overcome
“patrimonialism” or the biological propensity to favour clan, kin and family,
this natural desire is the foremost type of political decay, which bedevils
Afghanistan or Somalia today, as well as felling countless great empires.
Fukuyama’s
book is neither Eurocentric nor monocausal, and he blends high theoretical
skills with the dense description much favoured by anthropologists and
historians. This means his book is a extremely detailed read, with a lot of
scattered history to enable the reader to navigate the basic details of Han or
Ming China.
Bypassing
ancient Egypt, Greece and Rome, he starts with ancient Chinese emperors who
ruled through a meritocratic mandarin elite, selected by written examinations.
When that exhibited signs of decay, the emperors introduced a network of eunuch
spies to counteract it. By contrast, India never developed a powerful central
state, except when foreigners imported it, which may explain why the democratic
prospects of India are a great deal better than those of its northern
neighbour.
He moves on
to the Abbasid caliphs and Ottoman Turks, who used abducted slaves, called
Mamluks and Janissaries, as soldiers and administrators. These men lacked any blood ties to the
tribes, and could not pass on their offices to their children, and thus would
not in theory be susceptible to patrimonialism, and be entirely to loyal to the
state.
In Europe,
Fukuyama highlights the role of the Roman Catholic Church in eradicating tribal
customs, particularly pertaining to inheritance, and in instituting both the
rule of law and separation of temporal and spiritual powers.
By the 18th
century, the key elements of modern political order were discernible in one
part of the world or other. China had an exceptionally strong state of great
venerability. India, the Middle East and Europe had the rule of law. Britain
and Denmark had developed accountable government. The rest of modern history is
a game of catch up, as the combination of these three factors replicate and
ramify throughout the world.
This book
was truly eye-opening and I have already begun reading the second volume: ‘Political
Order and Political Decay’. The lessons
contained within this book allows the reader to contextualise everything from
the National Grid to the Syrian Civil War.
It thus merits 5/5.
Comments
Post a Comment